Professor of Behavioral Science and Economics
Vasilou Faculty Scholar

University of Chicago, Booth School of Business

NBER Faculty Research Associate
CESifo Research Network Fellow
Center for Applied Artificial Intelligence, Faculty Affiliate
Human Capital & Economic Opportunity, Faculty Affiliate

Research Interests
Behavioral Economics, Behavioral Finance, Judgment and Decision Making

Contact Information
(224) 392-3669
alex.imas@chicagobooth.edu

Alex Imas studies behavioral economics with a focus on cognition and mental representation in dynamic decision-making. His research explores topics related to choice under uncertainty, discrimination, and how people learn from information. Professor Imas’ work utilizes a variety of methods, including lab experiments, field experiments, analysis of observational data and theoretical modeling.

Alex Imas is the recipient of the 2023 Alfred P. Sloan Research Fellowship, the Review of Financial Studies Rising Scholar Award, the New Investigator Award from the Behavioral Science and Policy Association, the Hillel Einhorn New Investigator Award from the Society of Judgment and Decision Making, the Distinguished CESifo Affiliate Award, and the NSF Graduate Research Fellowship. He is an Associate Editor at the Journal of the European Economic Association.

An overview of his research agenda can be found here: [Link]

His faculty webpage can be found here: [Link]

Data, experimental instructions and supplementary materials for all published papers can be accessed on my Open Science Framework profile or the journal’s website.

Attention, Learning, and Belief-Formation

1. "A Cognitive Foundation for Perceiving Uncertainty," with J. A. Bohren, J. Hascher, M. Ungeheuer, and M. Weber
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

We propose a framework where perceptions of uncertainty are driven by the interaction between cognitive constraints and the way that people learn about it --- whether information is presented sequentially or simultaneously. People can learn about uncertainty by observing the distribution of outcomes all at once (e.g., seeing a stock return distribution) or sampling outcomes from the relevant distribution sequentially (e.g., experiencing a series of stock returns). Limited attention leads to the overweighting of unlikely but salient events --- the dominant force when learning from simultaneous information --- whereas imperfect recall leads to the underweighting of such events --- the dominant force when learning sequentially. A series of studies show that, when learning from simultaneous information, people are overoptimistic about and are attracted to assets that exhibit large but unlikely outperformance. However, they overwhelmingly select more consistently outperforming assets when learning the same information sequentially, and this is reflected in beliefs. The entire 40-percentage point preference reversal is driven by limited attention and memory; manipulating these factors completely eliminates the effect of the learning environment on choices and beliefs, and can even reverse it.

2. "Over- and Underreaction to Information," with C. Ba and J. A. Bohren
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

This paper explores how properties of the learning environment determine how people react to information. We develop a two-stage model of belief formation where people first reduce complexity by channeling attention to a subset of states that are representative of the observed information, then evaluate this information using Bayes’ rule subject to cognitive imprecision. The model predicts overreaction when environments are complex, signals are noisy, or priors are concentrated on intermediate states; it predicts underreaction when environments are simple, signals are precise, or priors concentrated on more extreme states. Results from a series of pre-registered experiments provide direct support for these predictions, as well as the proposed attentional mechanism. We show that the two-stage model is highly complete in capturing explainable variation in belief-updating; in particular, the interaction between the two psychological mechanisms is critical to explaining belief-formation in more complex settings. These results connect disparate findings in prior work: underreaction is typically found in laboratory studies, which feature simple learning settings, while overreaction is prevalent in financial markets, which feature more complex environments.

3. "Selling Fast and Buying Slow: Heuristics and Trading Performance of Institutional Investors," with K. Akepanidtaworn, R. Di Mascio, and L. Schmidt. Journal of Finance, 2023. (Lead Article)
[Abstract] [Working Paper] [Media Summaries: Bloomberg (Matt Levine), Bloomberg (Barry Ritholtz), Barron's, The Economist]

Are market experts prone to heuristics, and if so, do they transfer across closely related domains --- buying and selling? We investigate this question using a unique dataset of institutional investors with portfolios averaging $573 million. A striking finding emerges: while there is clear evidence of skill in buying, selling decisions underperform substantially --- even relative to random selling strategies. This holds despite the similarity between the two decisions in frequency, substance and consequences for performance. Evidence suggests that an asymmetric allocation of cognitive resources such as attention can explain the discrepancy: we document a systematic, costly heuristic process when selling but not when buying.

4. "Ownership, Learning, and Beliefs," with S. Hartzmark and S. Hirshman. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2021
[Abstract] [Working Paper] [Media Summaries: Chicago Booth Review ]

We examine how owning a good affects learning and beliefs about its quality. We show that people have more extreme reactions to information about a good that they own compared to the same information about a non-owned good: ownership causes more optimistic beliefs after receiving a positive signal and more pessimistic beliefs after receiving a negative signal. Comparing learning to normative benchmarks reveals that people over-extrapolate from signals about goods that they own, which leads to an overreaction to information; in contrast, learning is close to Bayesian for non-owned goods. We provide direct evidence that this effect is driven by ownership channeling greater attention towards associated information, which leads people to overweight recent signals when forming beliefs. The relationship between ownership and beliefs has testable implications for trade and market expectations. In line with these predictions, we show that the endowment effect doubles in response to positive information and disappears with negative information, and demonstrate a significant relationship between ownership and over-extrapolation in survey data about stock market expectations.

Dynamic Decision-Making

1. "Reversals Between One-Shot and Repeated Decisions in Incentive Design: The Case of Regret," with F. Araujo and A. Wilson. Revision requested at Journal of Political Economy Microeconomics
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

We demonstrate potential pitfalls when extrapolating behavioral findings identified from one-shot choices to repeated settings. As a case study, we examine the use of “regret lotteries” as a behavioral tool to boost motivation. Based on findings from one-shot settings, presenting counterfactual information generates the potential for regret, which can be used to increase a lottery’s value. This result has motivated the increasing use of “regret lotteries” in the field to incentivize recurrent decisions like exercise and compliance with company directives. Using a controlled experiment we show that while regret lotteries are the superior motivational tool in one-shot decisions, for repeated decisions the effect is entirely reversed. These findings have implications for incentive and policy design, highlighting the scope for error when extrapolating one-shot findings to inherently repeated settings.

2. "Dynamic Inconsistency in Risky Choice: Evidence from the Lab and Field," with R. Heimer, Z. Iliewa and M. Weber. American Economic Review, accepted.
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

We document a dynamic inconsistency in risky choice. Using a unique brokerage dataset and two preregistered experiments, we compare people's initial risk-taking plans to their subsequent decisions. In both settings, people accept risk as part of a ''loss-exit" strategy---planning to continue taking risk after gains and stopping after losses. Actual behavior follows the reverse pattern, deviating from initial strategies by cutting gains early and chasing losses. More individuals accept risk when offered a commitment to their initial strategy. Our results help reconcile seemingly contradictory findings on risk-taking in static versus dynamic contexts. We discuss implications for theory and welfare.

3. "Biased By Choice: How Financial Constraints Can Reduce Financial Mistakes," with R. Heimer. Review of Financial Studies, 2021.
Review of Financial Studies Rising Scholars Award
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

We show that constraints can improve financial decision-making by disciplining behavioral biases. In financial markets, restrictions on leverage limit traders' ability to borrow to open new positions. We demonstrate that regulation which restricts the provision of leverage to retail traders increases trading performance. By increasing the opportunity cost of postponing the realization of losses, leverage constraints improve traders' market timing and reduce their disposition effect. We replicate these findings in two distinct experimental settings, further isolating the mechanism and demonstrating generality of the results. The interaction between constraints and behavioral biases has implications for policy and choice architecture.

4. "Realization Effect: Risk-Taking After Realized versus Paper Outcomes," American Economic Review, 2016.
Society of Judgment and Decision-Making Hillel-Einhorn Award
CESifo Distinguished Affiliate Award
INFORMS Decision Analysis Society Best Publication Award, finalist

[Abstract] [Paper] [Online Appendix] [Metadata]

Understanding how prior outcomes affect risk attitudes is critical for the study of choice under uncertainty. A large literature documents the significant influence of prior losses on risk attitudes. The findings appear contradictory: some studies find greater risktaking after a loss, whereas others show the opposite – that people take on less risk. I reconcile these seemingly inconsistent findings by distinguishing between realized versus paper losses. Using new and existing data, I replicate prior findings and demonstrate that following a realized loss, individuals avoid risk; if the same loss is not realized, a paper loss, individuals take on greater risk.

Discrimination

1. "Systemic Discrimination: Theory and Measurement," with J. A. Bohren and P. Hull
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

Economics often defines and measures discrimination as disparities arising from the direct effect of group identity. We develop new tools to model and measure systemic discrimination, which captures how discriminatory decisions in other domains—past, future, or contemporaneous—contribute to disparities in a given decision. We show that systemic discrimination can be driven by disparate signaling technologies or differential opportunities for skill development. We then propose a new measure based on a decomposition of total discrimination into direct and systemic components, and show how it can be used to estimate systemic discrimination in both experimental and observational data. We illustrate these new tools in three applications, including a novel Iterated Audit experimental paradigm with real hiring managers. The applications also identify behavioral frictions that blunt the impact of individual-level interventions and perpetuate systemic discrimination, suggesting the need for systems-based policy responses to systemic discrimination.

2. "Inaccurate Statistical Discrimination: An Identification Problem," with J. A. Bohren, K. Haggag and D. Pope. Accepted, Review of Economics and Statistics
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

Discrimination—differential treatment by group identity—is widely studied in economics. Its source is often categorized as taste-based or statistical (belief-based)—a valuable distinction for policy design and welfare analysis. We argue that in many situations, individuals may have inaccurate beliefs about the relevant characteristics of different groups. This possibility creates an identification problem when isolating the source of discrimination. When not accounted for, we show both theoretically and experimentally that such inaccurate statistical discrimination will be misclassified as taste-based. A review of the empirical discrimination literature in economics reveals the scope of this issue: a small minority of papers—fewer than 7%—consider inaccurate beliefs. We then examine two alternative methodologies for differentiating between these three sources of discrimination—varying the amount of information presented to evaluators and eliciting evaluators’ beliefs. We propose a possible intervention: when presented with accurate information, we show that inaccurate statistical discrimination decreases.

3. "The Dynamics of Discrimination: Theory and Evidence," with J. A. Bohren and M. Rosenberg. American Economic Review, 2019. (Lead Article)
2020 Exeter Prize for the best paper published in Experimental Economics, Behavioural Economics, and Decision Theory
[Abstract] [Paper]

We model the dynamics of discrimination and show how its evolution can identify the underlying source. We test these theoretical predictions in a field experiment on a large online platform where users post content that is evaluated by other users on the platform. We assign posts to accounts that exogenously vary by gender and evaluation histories. With no prior evaluations, women face significant discrimination. However, following a sequence of positive evaluations, the direction of discrimination reverses: women’s posts are favored over men’s. Interpreting these results through the lens of our model, this dynamic reversal implies discrimination driven by biased beliefs.

4. "The Language of Discrimination: Using Experimental versus Observational Data," with J. A. Bohren and M. Rosenberg. American Economic Association: Papers and Proceedings, 2018.
[Abstract] [Paper]

We use experimental and observational data to examine whether people respond differently to questions posed by females versus males. We document significant differences in the language of responses, both in terms of the distribution of language utilized, and the sentiment of this language (positive or negative). In the observational data, we also document differences in the language and sentiment of questions posed by gender. This highlights the importance of using experimental data to identify the causal role that gender plays in influencing the language choice of individuals responding to questions from males versus females.

Cognition and Mental Representation

1. "The Impact of Joint Versus Separate Prediction Mode on Forecasting Accuracy: The Role of Mental Models," with M. Jung, S. Saccardo, and J. Vosgerau
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

Forecasters predicting how people change their behavior in response to a treatment or participating in the intervention often consider a set of alternatives. In contrast, those who are treated are typically exposed to only one of the treatment alternatives. For example, managers selecting a wage schedule consider a set of alternative wages while employees are hired at a given rate. We show that forecasts made in Joint-prediction mode—which considers a set of alternatives—generate predictions that expect substantially larger behavioral responses than those made in Separate-prediction mode—which considers the response to only one treatment realization in isolation. Results show the latter to be more accurate in matching people’s actual responses to interventions and treatment changes. Our findings suggest that the discrepancy in accuracy is due to a disparity in the mental models used by forecasters and those being treated. We present applications to managerial decision-making and forecasting of scientific results.

2. "Can’t wait to pay: The desire for goal closure increases impatience for costs," with A. Roberts and A. Fishbach. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 2023.
[Abstract] [Paper]

We explore whether the desire to achieve psychological closure on a goal creates impatience. If so, people should choose an earlier (vs. later) option even when it does not deliver a reward. For example, they may prefer to pay money or complete work earlier rather than later. A choice to incur earlier costs seems to violate the preference for positive discounting (indeed, it may appear like negative time discounting), unless people value earlier goal closure. Across seven studies we consistently find that people preferred to pay more money sooner over less money later (Study 1) and complete more work sooner over less work later (Studies 2-5) more when they had a stronger desire for goal closure, such as when the sooner option allowed them to achieve goal closure and when the goal would otherwise linger on their minds (compared to when it would not). The implications of goal closure extend to impatience for gains (Studies 6-7), as people preferred less money sooner (vs. more later) when it allowed them to achieve goal closure. These findings suggest that the desire to achieve goal closure is an important aspect of time preferences. Taking this desire into account can explain marketplace anomalies and inform interventions to reduce impatience.

3. "Behavioral Food Subsidies," with A. Brownback and M. Kuhn. Review of Economics and Statistics, 2023.
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

We conduct a pre-registered field experiment with low-income grocery shoppers to study how behavioral interventions can improve the effectiveness of healthy food subsidies. Our unique design enables us to elicit choices and deliver subsidies both before and at the point of purchase. We examine the effects of two non-restrictive changes to the choice environment: giving shoppers a choice over the type of subsidy they receive and introducing a waiting period before the shopping trip to prompt deliberation about the food purchase decision. Combined, our interventions substantially improve the effectiveness of subsidies, increasing healthy purchases by 61% relative to a choice-less subsidy restricted to healthy food, and 199% relative to an un-subsidized control group. We discuss how these low-cost, scalable interventions can help mitigate nutritional inequality.

4. "On the Role of Similarity in Mental Accounting and Hedonic Editing," with E. Evers and C. Kang. Psychological Review, 2021.
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

The theory of mental accounting is often used to understand how people evaluate multiple outcomes or events. However, a model predicting which outcomes are associated with the same mental account and evaluated jointly, versus different accounts and evaluated separately, has remained elusive. We develop a framework that incorporates an online, bottom-up process of similarity and categorization into mental accounting operations. In this categorization-based model of mental accounting, outcomes that overlap on salient attributes are automatically categorized and assigned to the same mental account while outcomes that do not overlap on salient attributes are assigned to different accounts. We use this model to derive the hedonic accounting hypothesis, which generates testable behavioral predictions on people’s preferences over the timing of outcomes given similarity-based constraints on mental accounting operations. Six studies provide support for the predictions: People prefer to experience similar losses close together in time and spread dissimilar losses apart; the reverse is true for gains, with a preference for dissimilar gains close together in time and similar gains spread apart across time. Importantly, our model is able to rationalize prior evidence that has found only limited support for the predictions of mental accounting and hedonic editing. Once the psychological process of similarity and categorization is explicitly incorporated into a formal model of mental accounting, its predictions are supported by the data.

5. "Waiting to Choose: The Role of Deliberation in Intertemporal Choice," with M. A. Kuhn and V. Mironova. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2021.
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

We study the impact of deliberation on intertemporal choices. Using multiple experiments, including a field study in the Democratic Republic of Congo, we show that the introduction of waiting periods—a policy that temporally separate information about choices from choices themselves—cause substantially less myopic decisions. These results cannot be captured by models of exponential discounting nor present bias. Comparing the effects of waiting periods to making planned choices over future time periods, the former has a larger impact on reducing myopia. Our results highlight the role of deliberation in decision-making and have implications for policy and intervention design.

6. "Mental Money Laundering: A Motivated Violation of Fungibility," with G. Loewenstein and C. K. Morewedge. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2021.
[Abstract] [Working Paper] [Media Summaries: Chicago Booth Review ]

People exploit flexibility in mental accounting to relax psychological constraints on spending. Four studies demonstrate this in the context of moral behavior. The first study replicates prior findings that people donate more money to charity when they earned it through unethical versus ethical means. However, when the unethically-earned money is first “laundered”––the cash is physically exchanged for the same amount but from a different arbitrary source—people spent it as if it was earned ethically. This mental money laundering represents an extreme fungibility violation: exchanging “dirty” money for the same sum coming from a “clean” source significantly changed people’s propensity to spend it prosocially. The second study demonstrates that mental money laundering generalizes to cases in which ethically and unethically earned money is mixed. When gains from ethical and unethical sources were pooled, people spent the entire pooled sum as if it was ethically earned. The last two studies provide mixed support for the prediction that people actively seek out laundering opportunities for unethically earned money, suggesting partial sophistication about these effects. These findings provide new evidence for the ease with which people can rationalize misbehavior, and have implications for consumer choice, corporate behavior and public policy.

7. "The Impact of Agency on Time and Risk Preferences," with A. Gneezy and A. Jaroszewicz. Nature: Communications, 2020.
[Abstract] [Paper]

Scholars have long argued for the central role of agency—the size of one’s choice set—in the human experience. We demonstrate the importance of agency in shaping people’s preferences. We first examine the effects of resource scarcity—which has been associated with both impatience and a lack of agency—on patience and risk tolerance, successfully replicating the decrease in patience among those exposed to scarcity. Critically, however, we show that endowing individuals with agency over scarcity fully moderates this effect, increasing patience substantially. We further demonstrate that agency’s impact on patience is partly driven by greater risk tolerance. These results hold even though nearly all individuals with greater agency do not exercise it, suggesting that merely knowing that one could alleviate scarcity is sufficient to change behavior. We then demonstrate that the effects of agency generalize to other adverse states, highlighting the potential for agency-based policy and institutional design.

8. "Is Altruism Sensitive to Scope? The Role of Tangibility," with G. Loewenstein. American Economic Association: Papers and Proceedings, 2018.
[Abstract] [Paper]

Prior work has shown that people appear insensitive to the scope of their altruistic acts and prosocial behavior. While they respond positively when their choices lead to increasing rewards for themselves, people do not change their behavior when the outcomes for others increase. We demonstrate that the scope sensitivity of altruism depends critically on its tangibility, and suggest that this relationship operates through mental accounting. We show that by increasing the level of tangibility, people can become just as sensitive to changes in the size of rewards for others as if they were earning the rewards themselves.

9. "Do People Anticipate Loss Aversion?" with S. Sadoff and A. Samek. Management Science, 2016.
[Abstract] [Paper]

There is growing interest in the use of loss contracts that offer performance incentives as upfront payments that employees can lose. Standard behavioral models predict a tradeoff in the use of loss contracts: employees will work harder under loss contracts than under gain contracts; but, anticipating loss aversion, they will prefer gain contracts to loss contracts. In a series of experiments, we test these predictions by measuring performance and preferences for payoff-equivalent gain and loss contracts. We find that people indeed work harder under loss than gain contracts, as the theory predicts. Surprisingly, rather than a preference for the gain contract, we find that people actually prefer loss contracts. In exploring mechanisms for our results, we find suggestive evidence that people do anticipate loss aversion but select into loss contracts as a commitment device to improve performance.

Social Behavior and Strategic Interactions

1. "Superiority-Seeking and the Preference for Exclusion," with K. Madarasz. Review of Economic Studies, 2023.
[Abstract] [Working Paper] [Media Summaries: Chicago Booth Review, The Equation]

We propose that a person’s desire to consume an object or possess an attribute increases in how much others want but cannot have it. We term this motive superiority-seeking, and show that it generates preferences for exclusion that help explain a host of market anomalies and make novel predictions in a variety of domains. In bilateral exchange, there is a reluctance to trade, leading to an endowment effect. People’s value of consuming a good increases in its scarcity, which generates a motive for firms and organizations to engage in exclusionary policies. A monopolist producing at constant marginal cost can increase profits by randomly excluding buyers relative to the standard optimal mechanism of posting a common price. In the context of auctions, a seller can extract greater revenues by randomly barring a subset of consumers from bidding. Moreover, such non-price-based exclusion leads to higher revenues than the classic optimal sales mechanism. A series of experiments provides direct support for these predictions. In basic exchange, a person’s willingness to pay for a good increases as more people are explicitly barred from the opportunity to acquire it. In auctions, randomly excluding people from the opportunity to bid substantially increases bids amongst those who retain this option. Consistent with our predictions, exclusion leads to bigger gains in expected revenue than increasing competition through inclusion. Our model of superiority-seeking generates ‘Veblen effects,’ rationalizes attitudes against redistribution, and provides a novel motive for social exclusion and discrimination.

2. "The Psychology of Negative-Sum Behavior in Strategic Interactions," with C. Hsee, Y. Zeng, and X. Li. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 2023.
[Abstract] [Paper]

Many real-life examples—from interpersonal rivalries to international conflicts—suggest that people actively engage in competitive behavior even when it is negative-sum (benefiting the self at a greater cost to others). This often leads to loss spirals where everyone—including the winner—ends up losing. Our research seeks to understand the psychology of such negative-sum behavior in a controlled setting. To do so, we introduce an experimental paradigm in which paired participants have the option to repeatedly perform a behavior that causes a relatively small gain for the self and a larger loss to the other. Although they have the freedom not to engage in the behavior, most participants actively do so and incur substantial losses. We propose that an important reason behind the phenomena is shallow-thinking—focusing on the immediate benefit to the self while overlooking the downstream consequences of how the behavior will influence their counterparts’ actions. In support of the proposition, we find that participants are less likely to engage in negative-sum behavior if they are advised to consider the downstream consequences of their actions, or if they are put in a less frenzied decision environment, which facilitates deeper thinking (acting in discrete versus continuous time). We discuss how our results differ from prior findings and the implications of our research for mitigating negative-sum competition and loss spirals in real life.

3. "Bounded Rationality in Strategic Decisions: Undershooting in a Resource Pool-Choice Dilemma," with C. Hsee, Y. Zeng, and X. Li. Management Science, 2021.
[Abstract] [Paper]

This research studies a resource pool-choice dilemma, in which a group of resource seekers independently choose between a larger pool containing more resources and a smaller pool containing fewer resources, knowing that the resources in each pool will be divided equally among its choosers, so that the more (fewer) people choose a certain pool, the fewer (more) resources each of them will get. This setting corresponds to many real-world situations, ranging from students choosing majors as a function of job opportunities to entrepreneurs choosing markets as a function of customer bases. Ten studies reveal a systematic undershooting bias: fewer people choose the larger pool relative to both the normative equilibrium benchmark and chance (random choice), thus advantaging those who chose the larger pool and disadvantaging those who chose the smaller pool. We present evidence that the undershooting bias is driven by bounded rationality in strategic thinking, and discuss the relationship of our paradigm with other coordination games.

4. "Conscience Accounting: Emotion Dynamics in Social Behavior," with U. Gneezy and K. Madarasz. Management Science, 2014.
[Abstract] [Paper]

This paper presents theory and experiments where people's prosocial attitudes fluctuate over time following the violation of an internalized norm. We report the results of two experiments in which people who first made an immoral choice were then more likely to donate to charity than those who did not. In addition, those who knew that a donation opportunity would follow the potentially immoral choice behaved more unethically than those who did not know. We interpret this increase in charitable behavior as being driven by a temporal increase in guilt induced by past immoral actions. We term such behavior conscience accounting and discuss its importance in charitable giving and in the identification of social norms in choice behavior through time inconsistency.

5. "The Materazzi Effect and the Strategic Use of Anger," with U. Gneezy. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 2014.
[Abstract] [Paper]

We propose that individuals use anger strategically in interactions. We first show that in some environments angering people makes them more effective in competitions, whereas in others, anger makes them less effective. We then show that individuals anticipate these effects and strategically use the option to anger their opponents. In particular, they are more likely to anger their opponents when anger negatively affects the opponents’ performances. This finding suggests people understand the effects of emotions on behavior and exploit them to their advantage.

6. "Paying to be Nice: Costly Prosocial Behavior and Consistency," with A. Gneezy, L.D. Nelson, M.I. Norton and A. Brown. Management Science, 2012.
[Abstract] [Paper]

Building on previous research in economics and psychology, we propose that the costliness of initial prosocial behavior positively influences whether that behavior leads to consistent future behaviors. We suggest that costly prosocial behaviors serve as a signal of prosocial identity and that people subsequently behave in line with that self-perception. In contrast, costless prosocial acts do not signal much about one’s prosocial identity, so subsequent behavior is less likely to be consistent and may evenshow the reductions in prosocial behavior associated with licensing. The results of a laboratory experiment and a large field experiment converge to support our account.

Incentives and Behavior Change

1. "Are Non-Contingent Incentives More Effective in Motivating New Behavior? Evidence from the Field," with D. Schwartz and A. Cordova. Games and Economic Behavior, 2021.
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

Companies and policymakers are increasingly relying on economic incentives as a means of promoting new habits and changing people’s behavior. For example, workplace wellness programs use incentives to encourage a healthier lifestyle and municipalities offer financial incentives to fund recycling programs. The goal of these incentives is to motivate previous non-compliers---to prompt participation amongst those that they were not engaged in an activity before. We ran a field experiment with a recycling program to examine which types of incentives are more effective in motivating new behavior---in our context, attracting previous non-recyclers. We compared the effects of standard incentives (payment contingent on recycling) to non-contingent incentives (upfront unconditional payment). We found that a high contingent incentive was as effective as a non-contingent incentive (of any size) in getting people to participate in the program, but this masked substantial differences in who participated. Over 50% of those participating under non-contingent incentives were new recyclers, compared to less than 15% under contingent incentives. This difference was particularly stark when incentives were relatively small: 53% of participants under non-continent incentives had never recycled before, compared to 0 new recyclers under contingent incentives. Follow-up surveys provide suggestive evidence that non-contingent incentives were effective in prompting persistent behavior change. A second experiment conceptually replicated this effect in an online job market, showing that non-contingent incentives were substantially more effective in attracting previous non-compliers.

2. "Opting In to Prosocial Incentives," with D. Schwartz, E. A. Keenan and A. Gneezy. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 2019.
[Abstract] [Paper] [Online Appendix]

The design of effective incentive schemes that are both successful in motivating employees and keeping down costs is of critical importance. Research has demonstrated that prosocial incentives – where individuals’ effort benefits a charitable organization – can sometimes be more effective than standard monetary incentives. However, most research has focused on the intensive margin, assuming that participation in the activity (whether voluntary or mandatory) is certain. We examine the effect of prosocial incentives on people’s decision to opt-in to an incentivized activity offering an optional prosocial incentive. By not restricting a participant’s choice set, optional prosocial incentives act as a nudge that combines the effectiveness of both standard and prosocial incentives. Across four experiments that vary incentive size, we find that individuals are more likely to avoid activities that involve any prosocial incentive. Our results highlight the importance of considering the environment and conditions necessary for successful design and implementation of nudges.

3. "Working for the 'Warm Glow': On the Benefits and Limits of Prosocial Incentives." Journal of Public Economics, 2013.
[Abstract] [Paper]

We study whether using prosocial incentives, where effort is tied directly to charitable contributions, may lead to better performance than standard incentive schemes. In a real-effort task, individuals indeed work harder for charity than for themselves, but only when incentive stakes are low. When stakes are raised, effort increases when individuals work for themselves but not when they work for others and, as a result, the difference in provided effort disappears. Individuals correctly anticipate these effects, choosing to work for charity at low incentives and for themselves at high incentives. The results are consistent with warm glow giving and have implications for optimal incentive design.

Methods

1. "Time Preferences and Food Choice," with A. Brownback and M. Kuhn.
[Abstract] [Working Paper]

Healthy food choices are a canonical example used to illustrate the importance of time preferences in behavioral economics. However, the literature lacks a direct demonstration that they are well-predicted by incentivized time preference measures. We offer direct evidence by combining a novel, two-question, incentivized time preference measurement with data from a field experiment that includes grocery purchases and consumption. Our present-focus measure is highly predictive of food choice, capturing a number of behaviors consistent with self-control problems, which provides direct evidence for the common assumption that important aspects of nutrition are driven by time preferences.

2. "Lab in the Field: Measuring Preferences in the Wild," with U. Gneezy. In Handbook of Field Experiments, Abhijit Banerjee and Esther Duflo, editors, 2017.
[Abstract] [Published Paper]

In this chapter, we discuss the “lab-in-the-field” methodology, which combines elements of both lab and field experiments in using standardized, validated paradigms from the lab in targeting relevant populations in naturalistic settings. We begin by examining how the methodology has been used to test economic models with populations of theoretical interest. Next, we outline how lab-in-the-field studies can be used to complement traditional Randomized Control Trials in collecting covariates to test theoretical predictions and explore behavioral mechanisms. We proceed to discuss how the methodology can be utilized to compare behavior across cultures and contexts, and test for the external validity of results obtained in the lab. The chapter concludes with an overview of lessons on how to use the methodology effectively.

3. "Experimental Methods: Eliciting Risk Preferences," with G. Charness and U. Gneezy. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 2013.
[Abstract] [Paper]

Economists and psychologists have developed a variety of experimental methodologies to elicit and assess individual risk attitudes. Choosing which to utilize, however, is largely dependent on the question one wants to answer, as well as the characteristics ofthe sample population. The goal of this paper is to present a series of prevailing methods for eliciting risk preferences and outline the advantages and disadvantages of each. We do not attempt to give a comprehensive account of allthe methods or nuances of measuring risk, but rather to outline some advantages and disadvantages of different methods.

Other Research

1. "Plasminogen Activator Inhibitor-1 Regulates Integrin αvβ3 Expression and Autocrine TGFβ Signaling," with B. S. Pedjora, L. E. Kang, P. Carmeliet and A. M. Bernstein. Journal of Biological Chemistry, 2009. [Published Paper]

2. "EEG-based Method for Biometric Identity Confirmation," with M. Milgramm. U.S. Patent No. 7,594,122. [Patent Document]

3. "EEG-based Method for Real Time Attitude Assessment," with M. Milgramm. U.S. Patent No. 7,570,991. [Patent Document]

4. "EEG-based Method for Attention and Productivity Monitoring," with M. Milgramm. U.S. Patent No. 7,574,254. [Patent Document]